Mboweni on 'Artistic science or scientific art?: The role of forecasting in
Monetary policy formulation' at the Reuters Economist of the Year Award,
Johannesburg
6 September 2007
Honoured guests
Ladies and gentlemen
1. Introduction
It is said that there are two kinds of economists: those who cannot
forecast, and those who do not know that they cannot forecast. We have to be
thick-skinned to be economists as we are often the butt of jokes. Apparently
there are more jokes about economists than any other profession, except perhaps
lawyers. It would appear that the negative perceptions that are held about
economists can be blamed to a large extent on economic forecasters who, we are
told, have accurately forecast eight of the last three recessions.
But forecasting is not always a joke, and the quality of the contestants of
the Reuters Economist of the Year competition is testament to that. Forecasting
is a serious and integral part of economic life. Any decision, whether an
investment decision or a policy decision, or in fact any decision in life that
involves taking a view on the future, has to be made on the basis of some
forecast. So if we regard forecasting as a joke, then the joke is on us.
Unfortunately we do not have perfect foresight and therefore we will never be
able to forecast perfectly. The best we can do is to strive to create
forecasting models that are close approximations of reality which in turn
provides a coherent and disciplined framework for making decisions. In my
comments to you this morning, I will discuss the role of forecasting and how we
use forecasts in the monetary policy decision making process.
2. Models and forecasts
There are different ways we can go about generating forecasts. Although
there may be some forecasters who engage in pure guesswork or thumb-sucking,
most forecasters would be informed by models with varying degrees of
sophistication. These could vary from simple extrapolation of the past, to
analysing current developments and assessing their implications for the future,
to a more complex dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model, which is the
latest fad among model builders. Forecasting success, however, is not
guaranteed by the level of sophistication of the model.
The type of model we use would, to some extent, depend on the time horizon
that we are interested in, as different models are better suited to different
forecast horizons. In the short run, momentum of data may be more important
than longer term structural and behavioural relationships. We therefore see
different types of forecasting strategies in the markets. For example, many
traders have time horizons of a few minutes. To them tomorrow is very long
term. Those needing short term forecasts will probably use chartist or
bottom-up spreadsheet techniques. These models have little basis in economic
theory, and are unlikely to perform well over longer term horizons. Our
structural models in the Bank, for example, use quarterly data, so by
definition they cannot be used for predicting one month ahead. For this we
would use autoregressive integrated moving average (Arima) models, which are
also momentum type models with no underlying economic theory. Predictions based
on Arima are used for short term predictions, and since they are based purely
on historical trends, they are not very good when it comes to predicting
turning points.
Some forecasters rely on simple correlations noted in the market. As we all
know, correlations do not imply a causal relationship or even any direct
relationship. The dangers of spurious correlations are well known. David
Hendry, the renowned Oxford University econometrician, in his appropriately
titled paper: "Forecasting: alchemy or science?" illustrated this perfectly
when he showed that there was a better relationship between inflation and the
cumulative rainfall in Scotland, than between inflation and monetary
aggregates. I do not know if this means that we should be employing Scottish
weather forecasters in the Bank to make our inflation forecasts. I am told,
however, that weather forecasters were created in order to make economic
forecasters look good.
3. Why are forecasts wrong?
Even if we do build sophisticated structural models incorporating good
behavioural relationships, the forecasts are still likely to be wrong. There
are various types of forecast errors. Firstly, there may be misspecification of
the model. This could mean that we have excluded one or more variables, or that
we have specified the wrong type of function. Our modelling team is continually
developing our models to try and overcome this type of problem. Secondly, there
may be structural breaks in the economy which are difficult to take account of
when estimating over a long time horizon. This means that there may be a bias
to the estimated coefficients of the model. This is particularly relevant to
South Africa given the transformation of the economy over the last decade or
more.
A third problem relates to data. Historical data are subject to measurement
error and are also revised after publication. In a number of instances we do
not have a consistent series going back far enough to ensure a more reliable
estimate of the parameters. In addition, some variables, such as the wealth or
expectations variables, have to be proxied. Inflation expectations are central
to the inflation formation process, yet modelling inflation expectations is a
major challenge.
While misspecified models, bad methods and inaccurate data are often blamed
for serious forecast errors, David Hendry argues that they are not the main
cause of systematic mistakes. Rather it is the unanticipated large changes or
shocks within the forecast period that are the primary source of errors. These
are totally unpredictable or idiosyncratic events that we simply cannot
predict, and in these instances the fault then lies in not rapidly adjusting
the forecasts once they become inconsistent with the exogenous shock. When
shocks occur, the best we can do is to adjust our forecasts accordingly. This
is why we should be constantly monitoring new developments.
There are instances where the risks to the forecast may be known but are
unquantifiable. The current round of financial market volatility is a case in
point. Although it was not a totally unpredictable shock, the timing was always
uncertain and we still do not know what the ultimate impact will be. Lawrence
Meyer, a former Federal Reserve Governor, in commenting on the Federal
Reserve's reactions to the financial market turbulence, said that the recent
shift in policy stance "tells us how difficult it is to translate financial
turbulence into macroeconomic forecast."
A model based forecast is only as good as the key assumptions that it is
based on. In the forecasting process of the Bank, a lot of time and effort is
dedicated to the process of deciding on the exogenous assumptions of the model.
Staff at various levels makes inputs but ultimately, about two to three weeks
in advance of the Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) meeting, the MPC members meet
to finalise the assumptions. Making assumptions about exogenous variables is an
important component of the forecasting process. But it is not always easy. Take
for example the international oil price for example. It is one of the most
important exogenous assumptions in our model and we have to formulate a view of
the price over the coming three years. Unpredictable geopolitical events,
hurricanes etc., will surprise us over the period and force us to change our
views. No matter how well we analyse the underlying market conditions, we are
likely to be wrong because of unpredictable events.
The difficulty of forecasting the oil price is well illustrated when
comparing the oil price forecasts of a number of different forecasters. For the
2008 forecast, the spread between the highest and lowest forecast in the market
is almost US$22 per barrel, and for 2009 the spread is slightly wider. If the
oil experts are so uncertain, how confident can we be? Yet this variable has a
critical bearing on the inflation outcome and the accuracy of our
forecasts.
One way we try and cope with this uncertainty is to consider various oil
price scenarios, so that we can see the sensitivity of the forecast to possible
changes in the exogenous variables. We then have to make a judgement call as to
which is the most likely scenario. As is the case with policy making,
forecasting is very often a science as well as an art.
4. The use of forecasts in monetary policy decision making
The Bank does not rely on a single model for its forecast. In line with most
central banks we have a suite of models that can be used for different purposes
and various time horizons. As I noted earlier, we use Arima models or vector
autoregressive (VAR) models for short term forecasting and for estimating
impulse responses. Other models include a disaggregated model which builds up
the inflation forecast from the individual components of CPIX independently,
which helps us identify the categories where price changes and inflationary
pressures have started to emerge. Finally, we have our main quarterly core
model which has 18 structural equations.
Policy, like investment decisions, has to be made on a forward looking
basis. As inflation targeters, we need to set interest rates on the basis of
our expectations of inflation over the next two years or so. This is
particularly the case given the lags in adjustment to interest rate changes.
The closer the model represents reality, the better it will be. However, as
outlined earlier, no model fully captures all the interrelationships in the
economy or captures expectations appropriately. Furthermore, as I outlined
earlier, idiosyncratic shocks cannot be forecast.
Much is made in the markets every month when new inflation data comes out.
To us the latest data point is only important to the extent that it may contain
clues to the future and that it gives us a new data point for the longer term
projection. The latest data point is in fact history. We can compare this to
driving a car. We do not drive a car by focusing only on the rear-view mirror.
That is a sure recipe for disaster. True, we have to look in the rear-view
mirror every now and again in case there is a bad driver bearing down on us,
but we should be generally looking ahead. Unfortunately, as with policy making,
the road ahead is not always clear.
For these reasons, it is not possible to use the forecast in a mechanical
way. Although in theory models should incorporate all available information at
any given point in time, there is still a certain amount of judgement that must
be used. So as policy makers, we cannot devolve our responsibilities to the
outcomes of the model. Much consideration has to be given to a thorough
analysis of the risks to the outlook. Even the most sophisticated models need
to be supplanted by anecdotal and other off-model information. As Federal
Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke recently remarked, "for all the advances that
have been made in modelling and statistical analysis, practical forecasting
continues to involve art as well as science."
Our most recent forecast that we reported on in the August MPC statement
suggests that we will be outside the target range until the second quarter of
next year, and then inflation will gradually decline. However this forecast is
only as good as the assumptions we have put in to the model. The sensitivity of
the forecast to oil price and exchange rate changes are well known, and any
unexpected changes in these or other variables will cause the forecast to
change. So there can be no guarantee that the forecast will be the same next
time. Forecasts cannot be followed in a mechanical fashion since relevant
off-model information has to be accounted for and the risks to the forecasts
assessed.
5. Forecasting and transparency
The global trend in recent years is towards increased transparency in
monetary policy formulation. This helps to make monetary policy more
predictable which, in turn, helps reduce volatility in markets and make forward
planning easier. We can debate about where to draw the line as to the limits of
transparency, but one of the new trends has been for central banks to publish
their forecasts as well as their forecasting models. For some time we have been
showing our central forecast and the associated fan chart in the Monetary
Policy Review (MPR) which we publish twice a year. This is the forecast
presented to the MPC at the most recent MPC meeting prior to the publication of
the MPR.
Furthermore, in our statements which are released after each MPC meeting, we
give details of the forecast so that market participants have a good idea of
the timing and level at which inflation is expected to change direction. We
also indicate where we expect inflation to be at the end of the forecast
period.
More recently we have also published our core model following numerous
requests from private sector analysts and forecasters. We have also provided an
assessment of the performance of the model over time which shows that the
Bank's model has performed well, particularly relative to other private sector
forecasts. The obvious question to ask is, should these analysts not also be
transparent with their models? Would it not improve the quality of debate or
assist in the development of better models if we could see how other
forecasters generate their forecasts? I have noted a deafening silence when I
raise this issue with market economists.
6. Conclusion
I will not attempt to forecast the winner of the competition. I congratulate
all of the contestants. The winner is the forecaster who has most accurately
forecast the month ahead inflation over the past year. Although forecasting
near term inflation is useful, as the Financial Times columnist, Sir Samuel
Brittan argued, this type of forecast tells us more about the present and the
recent past than about the future. From a monetary policy perspective, we are
primarily concerned with forecasting over a longer time horizon. There is
nothing monetary policy can do about the latest inflation numbers. Monetary
policy should be judged on whether appropriate actions are being taken today to
ensure that inflation will be within the target range in 18 to 24 months time.
For this we need to have a good medium term forecast to provide us with a
coherent framework.
Despite all the problems associated with forecasting, they remain integral
to policy decisions, and we will continue to use them. The models have become
increasingly sophisticated, but the future is inherently uncertain. At the same
time the economic and political environment has also become more challenging
and difficult to predict. Unfortunately, as is sometimes said, the future is
not what it used to be.
Thank you.
Issued by: South African Reserve Bank
6 September 2007
Source: South African Reserve Bank (http://www.reservebank.co.za)